Reaction to the FCC’s announcement yesterday that it was circulating new open Internet rules blazed, with many claiming that the FCC had dramatically shifted course and was set to kill net neutrality. The truth is that the FCC never endorsed the strongest versions of net neutrality and has hardly budged. The agency’s tentative plans don’t increase the distance between the idealized egalitarian net and the reality of a pay-to-play distribution system — they just expose the reality that the distance has been growing.
To the extent that we’ve had a neutral network, with ISPs transmitting all content on equal terms, it has not been legally required. Look at the Comcast-Netflix deal for preferential interconnection. This “peering” arrangement whereby Netflix pays more to ensure fast delivery of its content was never even covered by open Internet rules, much less forbidden.
Net neutrality proponents accuse the FCC of walking away from its 2010 Open Internet rules that the D.C. Circuit partially vacated in Verizon v. FCC earlier this year. In fact, these rules equivocated on the practices that the FCC now wants to permit: “commercially reasonable” payments from content providers to ISPs for preferential delivery. The Open Internet Order said this practice of paid prioritization “would raise significant cause for concern,” but it ultimately reserved judgment. Of course the nondiscrimination rules did not reach mobile and we have seen a number of paid prioritization deals in the mobile space, such as AT&T’s sponsored data program and the privileging of Google and Facebook on some mobile plans.
Without reclassification of internet transmission as a Title II telecommunications service, the FCC was never going to forbid deals that improved content delivery (and even under Title II, tiered pricing is not always “unreasonable discrimination.)” Where “best efforts” delivery is not good enough (often because the network is under-built), it’s hard to imagine a regulator standing in the way of a better consumer experience. The consumer benefits of course are often illusory and short-term. Consumers may end up paying more and having access to less diverse and innovative content. Apart from economic harms, there is harm to the potential future consumer experience foreclosed because some players never get the chance to play. The harm is to diversity – a concept that has long bedeviled U.S. media law. But this tradeoff between greater distant harms and smaller immediate benefits is not new. Nor is the direction the FCC announced this week.
The game will turn, as we always knew it would, on the meaning of “commercially reasonable” pricing practices. About this, I’ll have more to say in another post. We know from Section 616 of the 1992 Cable Act that proving unreasonably discriminatory carriage of cable channels is extremely hard, expensive, and protracted. If there is to be any bite in rules preventing unreasonable discrimination on broadband networks, it will be crucially important to develop a different, faster procedure that shifts the burden to the network operator. The other thing that net neutrality advocates have to focus on, as I’ve said here and here, are various components of public broadband. We know what highly commercialized content distribution systems look like. Progressives have pushed back to build noncommercial alternatives. This has to be part of the response to networks that are ever more tied to a relentlessly commercial logic.